Navigation – Plan du site

AccueilNuméros10-4Economics as a Public Science, Pa...More of an Art than a Science: Th...

Economics as a Public Science, Part III

More of an Art than a Science: The IMF’s Debt Sustainability Analysis and the Making of a Public Tool

Plus un art qu’une science : l’analyse de soutenabilité de la dette par le FMI, ou la création d’un outil public
Christina Laskaridis
p. 789-818

Résumés

Cet article examine les origines de l’Analyse de Soutenabilité de la Dette (ASD), un modèle fait pour faciliter la mesure de viabilité de l’endettement d’un pays. Ce modèle a été introduit en 2003. Il offre un cadre prédéfini pour régir la façon dont les économistes du FMI doivent mener leurs analyses de soutenabilité de la dette. Cet article examine la manière dont la connaissance économique est conditionnée par ce modèle, et montre comment l’expertise a été façonnée pour solutionner les problèmes de légitimation du FMI. L’opinion publique apparaît comme un élément indispensable de ce processus. Les pratiques antérieures ont été publiquement ridiculisées parce que considérées comme peu fiables ; l’introduction du modèle ASD a tenté de les rendre comparables d’un pays à l’autre. Cet article montre que les fondements théoriques réels de l’analyse de soutenabilité de la dette ont eu moins d’importance que la façon dont le « public » les recevait. Au sein du Fonds, ce « public » a été perçu à travers la référence au « marché », aux gouvernements ainsi qu’à un contrôleur externe non défini. L’article utilise des documents d’archives du Conseil d’Administration pour montrer que la perception de la fiabilité de sa politique, qui repose à son tour sur une perception de la rigueur théorique sous-jacente, a été une source d’autorité importante pour le FMI, qui l’a utilisée dans le but de renforcer sa légitimité dans l’opinion publique.

Haut de page

Notes de la rédaction

Œconomia is pleased to publish the following two research articles, by Bert Tieben and Christina Laskaridis, as part of the symposium on “Economics and Public Reason.” These articles emerged from a conference hosted by the Centre Walras Pareto for the History of Economic and Political Thought at the University of Lausanne in early May 2018, other papers from which were published in the June and September 2019 issues of this journal.

Texte intégral

1The welcoming words of Stanley Fischer towards Indonesia’s decision to float its currency (Fischer, 1997) sparked controversy over the International Monetary Fund’s (IMF’s) handling of the South East Asian crisis. Jeffrey Sachs, for instance, reignited the debate about the legitimacy of the IMF’s interventions, commenting that instead of “dousing the fire” of the financial crisis spreading through Asian countries, the IMF “screamed fire in the theatre” (Sachs, 1998). Concerns about legitimacy have been usually premised on the IMF’s unequal governance structure and its policy advice. Covered widely in several works, the IMF’s legitimacy issues are often explored through the prism of political influence over the use of its resources (Breen, 2013; Buira, 2005; Momani, 2004; Thacker, 1999).

  • 1 In the IMF’s own account of its justification for policy: “there is surprisingly little readily acc (...)

2There is a consensus that the IMF is not free from various economic and political pressures, and this paper suggests that important aspects of these concerns are to be found in the role of economists and the way economic reasoning is applied to policy. The majority of the Fund’s staff are economists, who, inter alia develop policy tools to guide the organisation’s activities. Their role is crucial for they are the key experts within the organisation, both generating and operationalising economic knowledge. Described as “powerful and pervasive,” De Vriesa former official Fund historianconcluded that “professional economists, both in the staff and the Executive board, are the key instruments through which the International Monetary Fund develops and implements its policies” (De Vries, 1986, 65). While some have pointed to coalescence through professional training and epistemic communities that allow for the formation of an ideational consensus around market reform programmes (Babb, 2001; Chwieroth, 2007), others have shown the fluidity and divergence between policy and formal models (Bird, 1996; Spraos 1986), describing as it were, an “oral tradition” that has underpinned Fund policy (IMF, 1987, 1).1

  • 2 How ideas guide policy was often studied through the prism of ideology, a framework that drifted ou (...)

3Although the IMF’s policy design is rooted in economic expertise, the political complexity of IMF’s missions and operations makes difficult to disentangle the theoretical and policy aspects. In their comparative study of economists in international organisations, Endres and Fleming (2002, 5) noted that it is “not always possible to separate out the operational from the analytical dimension of work done by economists in international organisations.” This is at least partly due to the conceptual snares Donald Winch warned about, namely the danger of “an over-optimistic conception of the technocratic status of economics, and a naive view of the processes of political decision-making” (Winch, 1969, 19).2 In line with previous investigations of economists as experts (Coats, 1986; Mata and Medema, 2013), this article shows how the role of economists at the IMF goes beyond mere knowledge production. They are “doers,” communicators, problem makers and solvers. Drawing on the work of Harper (1998, 112), the Fund’s authority emerges through the production of IMF documents which “instruct as well as explain, they predict the future as well as account for the past.” An IMF document “is an artfully created document” (emphasis in original) arranged to enable expeditious response from the Board so that “Analysis … should be organised so that ‘what it ought to be’ is what was predicted beforehand” (Harper, 1998, 122, 113). This sheds light on how institutional habits are built through the day-to-day operational work of the organisation and how Fund economists build a kind of institutional authorship.

4This paper examines how economic knowledge is embedded in policy templates and shows how expertise is shaped to resolve the IMF’s legitimation problems. Barnett and Finnemore (2004), for instance, draw on Porter (2001) to examine how expertise, by appearing objective, is a defence to the longstanding accusations towards the Fund’s politicised behaviour. Existing work on the politics of knowledge within the Fund, identifies the use of policy templates as a source of “cognitive authority” and “indirect political power” (Broome and Seabrooke, 2011, 9). Seabrooke assesses whether policy templates used to benchmark the financial sector are “tools of domination in the quest for transparency” or whether these templates allow for a “pragmatic use of numbers” to allow for “reasoning and sense-making” (2012, 490, 500, 493). This paper draws out the role of the public as an indispensable aspect of how IMF expertise is shaped to resolve legitimacy problems by taking as a case study the creation of the IMF’s Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSA) template.

5The IMF’s Debt Sustainability Analysis (DSA) is a template to facilitate the measurement of a country’s debt sustainability that was introduced in 2002 and 2003 (IMF, 2002a; 2003). The template provides a pre-set format for guiding the way debt sustainability will be assessed by staff economists. This is a crucial policy area for the Fund; current policy prescribes that the IMF can only lend to its members if their debt is deemed sustainable in the medium term, and if it is not, the IMF is precluded from lending until restructuring or further concessional financing is secured (IMF, 2019). This paper shows the history of this policy device as arising from an attempt to correct previous practice that was publicly derided for being unsound. The introduction of the template attempted to make practices comparable across countries and to introduce a rules-bound quantification of access to Fund resources. This paper shows that the actual theoretical underpinnings of policy however are less important than how the ‘public’ perceived them. The paper uses archival material from the Executive Board from 2002 and 2003 to show that a significant rationale for introducing the DSA was to guide and quantify its decision making over the loan-giving process in order to attempt to constrain large loans and enhance its legitimacy in the public domain. This would arise from the perception of soundness in policy design, in turn relying on a perception of underlying theoretical rigour. Collective authorship is significant in raising the status and credibility of economic reasoning within and outside the Board, as a variety of audiences, as imagined by the Board, are drawn into policy design. Staff documents are written and presented to enhance the credibility of IMF expertise to external publics, and at the same time, the role of the public acts as a discipling device on IMF Staff. The paper first provides a brief overview of the Fund and its legitimacy issues in Section 1. Section 2 introduces the new policy, lays down its theoretical rationale and illustrates the template’s use. Section 3 covers some of the Board’s difficulties in applying theory in a practical setting. Section 4 discusses the introduction of the template to aide its decision-making process, Section 5 discusses the template as an internal disciplining device for Fund staff, and Section 6 as a public communication tool.

1. Problematic Governance

  • 3 For further information on the Executive Board and how voting power is allocated according to const (...)

6Governance structure is a longstanding source of criticism towards the Fund. Its senior organ is the Board of Governors, consisting of representatives from each member country, which delegates all but a few responsibilities to the Executive Board. The Executive Board represents all 185 member countries by grouping them into 24 constituencies where the voices of the single-country constituencies far outweigh those of the multi-country constituencies.3 While decisions at the Executive Board are made through a form of mood-sensing as opposed to voting (Gold, 1969, 517), the relative influence that a country has corresponds to each country’s assigned quotathe participation in the IMF’s capitalwhich favours higher income countries and gives effective veto power to the US (see Buira, 2005). A country’s quota determines the amount of financial support it is eligible to receive, governed by rules about access limits. As will be developed in subsequent sections, extraordinary loans beyond what would ordinarily be permitted through normal access limits created the need to quantify the criteria with which such access could be given.

7The IMF was initially set up in order to make its resources temporarily available to its members in need of balance of payments support (for a detailed account, see De Vries, 1987). Following the US suspension of gold convertibility in 1971 and the movement of countries off the adjustable peg system by 1973, the IMF’s role evolved into a more general financial crisis manager. The 1970s financial turmoil included the breakdown of Bretton Woods, but also the oil price and interest rate increases, which pushed much of the developing world into a debt crisis in the 1980s and a resulting ‘lost decade’ in development. The growing IMF’s involvement in crisis management was accompanied with far reaching conditionality programmes, which have since been the focus of most criticisms of the Fund’s influence on national policies. Such influence ranges from stipulating macro targets, for instance, on fiscal balances, to a perennially growing array of issues which include privatisation of public assets, liberalising trade and product markets, and a host of market reforms (for a review of Fund conditionality, see Babb and Buira, 2004; Kentikelenis, et al., 2016).

  • 4 Examples include Peru 1980 and 1984, Argentina 1983, and Brazil 1984. In Africa, in 1985, Julius Ny (...)
  • 5 Exceptions to this rule include Board minutes relating to members’ request for resources, where the (...)

8These broad programmes were rolled out with great social and political costs (Cornia et al., 1987). Across Latin America and Africa, governments fell frequently while trying to implement IMF programmes or resigned rather than accept them, often amidst widespread rioting with many casualties.4 In spite of the obvious influence of conditionality on borrowing countries, the details of IMF programmes as well as their economic rationale remained shrouded in mystery, if only because for the first fifty years of its existence, its constitution merely required the publication of one official document, the annual report (Chowla, 2007). This gave easy credence to the view of the IMF as a secretive institution, which, while something of an old adage, is still relevant if we compare it to other institutions of equivalent cloutsuch as the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee or the Federal Open Market Committee of the Federal Reserve, both of which publish minutes soon after policy decisions are made. The IMF still requires the passing of three full years before minutes of the Executive Board meetings can be made public, and even this is not always guaranteed.5

  • 6 The IMF’s handling of the South East Asian Crisis was heavily criticised for the politicisation of (...)

9In a series of capital account crises during the 1990s, the IMF provided loans far larger than what normal eligibility criteria would permit that were used to repay fleeing private creditors. The loan in Mexico (1994-1995) and the handling of the South East Asian crisis in the 1990s fragilised the IMF’s reputation. Hastily drafted draconian policy programmes (as in South Korea), the figure of Manging Director Michel Camdessus looming over Indonesia’s military leader and President Suharto while he signed a loan agreement, coupled with a narrative of the crisis later dubbed the ‘discursive demolition’ (Hall, 2003) of the Asian state-oriented development model, were, like previous crises, followed by growing poverty and civil unrest. The IMF was accused of bullying its members and of being secretive (see Driscoll and Clark, 2003) as well as being ideologically driven and ultimately undemocratic (Stiglitz, 2002).6

10Russia defaulted in 1998 amidst an IMF programme, and in 2001, the IMF decided to further increase Argentina’s already exceptionally large programme whilst the economy deteriorated amidst people’s seething fury. Economists in the Fund were divided given the whimsical credulity in the projected debt dynamics on which this decision was based (Blustein, 2006; IEO, 2004). These had assumed sustainability where none was forthcoming, as Argentina’s subsequent deposit freeze, default on its debt and abandonment of the fixed exchange indicated. The IMF’s reputational costs only multiplied.

  • 7 The relevant decision by the Board can be found in IMF (2002b).
  • 8 For the impact of subsequent crises on the IMF see Ban and Gallagher (2015), Clift (2018) and Stubb (...)

11These events generated a political desire inside the Fund not only to address the weak analysis that loan-giving relied on, but also to introduce policies to constrain large loans. This reinvigorated the debate on the ways in which countries are given access to IMF resources, prompting the IMF to reconsider the criteria a country needed to fulfil in order to gain extraordinarily large access to its resources. In the early 2000s, the IMF reconfigured the bar of exceptional access to standards that included a more rigorous assessment of debt sustainability.7 This could, in principle, provide grounds for the IMF to withhold financing absent of strong assurances of sustainability, and pressurise private creditors to accept reductions in their claims. In 2001, in the context of these debates, the first Deputy Managing Director Anne Krueger put forward a proposal of how countries’ debts could be reorganised when they are deemed unsustainable. Although this proposal was defeated, the creation of the DSA was intimately linked to this reconfiguration of the IMF’s role in crises.8

  • 9 The attempt by the IMF to address concerns about transparency is critically examined in Best (2005) (...)
  • 10 When a member of EXR published a pamphlet on the IMF’s organisation, evolution and activities in 19 (...)

12Along with these political changes that prompted the creation of the DSA, the crises of the late 1990s and early 2000 also forced the IMF to address demands for openness, transparency and accountability.9 The task went to the External Relations Department, whose rationale was to respond to a broader public making demands upon it and whose strategy was to try to educate the public so that its actions were better understood.10 For instance, the Public Information Notices (PINS) were inaugurated in 1997 in response to the East Asian crisis (IMF, 2001). The staff issued public summaries of the agreements between countries and the Fund, and offered the details of the IMF’s assessment of members’ policies to public scrutiny, and thus professional exposure to its policy advice (Soederberg, 2001). In response to the criticisms over its handling of the crises in Russia and Argentina, the IMF established the Independent Evaluation Office (IEO) to strengthen its external credibility (IEO, 2002). The same year, it allowed external access to a broad range of documents.

2. The Template and its Theoretical Rationale

  • 11 The template pertains to assessments of debt sustainability for countries with market access; for l (...)
  • 12 The IMF produces periodic country reports for countries that are in an IMF programme as well as ann (...)

13It was in this context that the IMF introduced a new framework to monitor the debt sustainability of its members.11 IMF (2002a; 2003) proposed to introduce debt sustainability analyses into all country reports.12 Having a way to form an opinion on whether a country’s debt will be repaid was key to the design of Fund’s programmes. Following the South East Asian crisis, the defaults in Russia and Argentina, the staff understood that judgements over loan size and repayment required a more rigorous and scientific basis. The DSA template was a means to attempt to provide the needed rigour.

  • 13 The dynamic budget constraint is solved through the transversality condition, a terminal condition (...)
  • 14 See IMF (2002, 5) for a fuller exposition.

14The template is organised around an externally provided macroeconomic baseline, which is used to produce a projected future time path of the annual debt-to-GDP ratio. The details of the underlying macro-framework that produce the baseline are not published in the DSA analysis. Rather, the DSA focuses on the debt-to-GDP ratio as a product of the evolution of the deficit, the growth rate, the interest rate, inflation and the exchange rate. The results are used to check whether the future path of the debt ratio is on a stable, declining or explosive path. The rationale for looking at the trajectory of the future debt-to-GDP ratio is provided by the economics of the intertemporal government budget. The debt is defined as sustainable if it fulfils a theoretical condition of solvency, that is, where expected future surpluses cover current debt. This captures the idea that current debts cannot be greater than what in present value terms all future primary balances must service.13 The solvency requirements are analytically identical whether referring to external or public debt sustainability so that when discussing the debt of a country or that of a government, sustainability is respectively linked to the evolution of the current account and the evolution of the budget deficit. Sustainability, thus defined, is a forward-looking idea, in which future primary balances matter. Accordingly, the balance (fiscal or non-interest current account) could develop in various ways and remain consistent with the solvency criterion. Therefore, within this formal definition, borrowers with any size of debt could be solvent as long as sufficient primary balances satisfying the solvency criterion arise at some point in the future.14

15The policy implementation of this theoretical rationale presented difficulties. The Fund’s measurement of debt sustainability was framed by the concerns of the Fund to provide its resources under adequate safeguards (i.e. conditionality) through its loan programmes and their repayment. The proposed policy template was to rest upon the debt dynamics equation to trace the future time path of the debt-to-GDP ratio over a specified time horizon. Initially, the suggested time horizon was for a minimum of five years, although this has since changed. The link to the theoretical rationale was that if the debt-to-GDP ratio was on a stable or declining path within the specific time horizon, the solvency criterion would be met.

  • 15 Over time, the template has become widely distributed and publicly available. The IMF has increased (...)

16The template was made available to country desk teams as an Excel file and remains to this day organised around two core sectionssee examples below.15 The primary section of the template lays out a baseline medium-term scenario of the evolution of the debt ratio. This was done using a set of assumptions about underlying macroeconomic variables which are compiled by the country desk economists. These are shown in Figure 1. The projected path of the debt ratio appears on Line 1, with changes in external debt referenced line 2, as a result of the summation of the next lines. Stock-flow adjustments are indicated in line 10.

Figure 1: External Debt Sustainability Analysis in Mexico’s 2003 Article IV Consultation

Figure 1: External Debt Sustainability Analysis in Mexico’s 2003 Article IV Consultation

Source: IMF (2004, 45)

  • 16 For the recent shift towards growth optimism and how this yields risky programmes by design see IMF (...)

17Medium-term projections of a country’s balance of payments and fiscal situation, although a long-time staple of IMF policy work, are conducted in a decentralised way. While the World Economic Outlook (WEO) is purported to produce a globally consistent projection, such was not the case of the individual country projections (IMF, 2002). These were produced by teams of economists working at the country or regional level who relied on local information, without a unified homogenous approach to making projections across countries, and where the underlying macro-framework is concealed from the public eye. While this enabled projections to be tailored to data availability across a great diversity of countries, there had been within and beyond the IMF a long-standing concern that some of these assumptions were biased.16 It was this bias that could enable less scrutiny over loan approval and bad policy advice. The new framework proposed a way for baseline macroeconomic projections to remain autonomously compiled by each country’s desk team, as previously, but introduced two novelties.

18The first was to make explicit the underlying macroeconomic assumptions on which IMF policy were grounded, while not revealing the way they were made nor proposing to homogenise the way projections were made across country desks. The second was to evaluate those underlying assumptions, by testing the sensitivity of the projected path to them. Figure 2 illustrates sensitivity tests to the key parameters of the baseline. These tests are conducted by setting key parameters to historical averages, and by shocking the macro variables separately and combined, by sizes that have been differently calibrated over time. For instance, instead of using assumptions of the baseline, the assumption could be that policy remains unchanged, by setting values to historical averages (Figure 2, Line 1), or that the country experiences a one-time depreciation shock (Figure 2, Line 7). This was done with the purpose of identifying possible underlying optimism in the baseline projection.

Figure 2: Stress Tests for External Debt Ratio in 2003 Mexico Article IV Consultation

Figure 2: Stress Tests for External Debt Ratio in 2003 Mexico Article IV Consultation

Source: IMF (2004, 45)

  • 17 The staff state that the precise formulation of the template is ongoing and subject to continuous m (...)

19The rationale for the approach was precisely to create a standardised template in which specifications such as the chosen length of time horizons, the type and size of shocks, and the calibration of the realism tests were homogenised. This would enable the practice of measuring debt sustainability and therefore the results of the exercises, to be comparable across countries.17 Finally, the information was presented in tables (such as Figure 1 and 2) and/or in figures comparing the evolution of debt ratio for various specifications as in Figure 3 (see IMF, 2003).

Figure 3: Example of a Visual Representation of Debt Sustainability Shocks

Figure 3: Example of a Visual Representation of Debt Sustainability Shocks

Source: IMF (2004, 19)

3. The Academic-to-Policy Tension

  • 18 Subsequent template vintages have sought to address some of the concerns.

20The fundamental concerns about the IMF’s attempt to measure debt sustainability are detailed in a flourishing academic and policy literature. These contributions emphasise the difficulty of adequately capturing a country’s ability to repay, one that is conditional upon a wider array of factors than the few macro variables included in the DSA. For instance, the DSA did not incorporate the volatility of commodity prices, a key determinant of export earnings which determine part of debt repayment abilities. The DSA did not indicate the overall composition of a country’s capital flows, even though short-term portfolio flows raise the danger of ‘sudden stops’ and currency crises. Other concerns included the lack of emphasis on contingent liabilities, in particular bank liabilities or other private debt bubbles that oftentimes end up being treated as fiscal problems. The accounting of government or country-level assets and the broader balance sheet was another criticism, as was the interaction between variables in debt dynamics (these and many more are raised in Nissanke and Ferrarini, 2004; Wyplosz, 2007; 2011; UNCTAD, 2009; Guzman and Heymann, 2015; Bonizzi et al., 2019).18 Further criticisms arise from the human rights implications of sovereign debt that reveal the narrowness of focusing on the ability to repay debts to the detriment of ability to provide basic social services (see Bantekas and Lumina, 2019; Lumina, 2013).

  • 19 Statements are referenced by the name of director(s) followed by the document type and are listed i (...)

21These concerns are echoed in the discussion at the first Executive Board meeting in 2002 that discussed the introduction of the template. The inherent uncertainty surrounding projections and the practical limitations created by data constraints led Directors to issue a chorus of warning towards the staff to proceed “with extreme care” (Portugal, GRAY/02/728).19 The focus on the trajectory of the debt-to-GDP ratio was criticised as insufficient to assess liquidity burdens of debt service that a country may face: the template does not capture the volatilities that export earnings or government revenue are exposed to. The choice of time horizon over which sustainability is judged is deemed too short, yet lengthened horizons could misrepresent structural change that countries may be experiencing. The Board also pointed that the template said little about how to interpret the starting level or finishing level of the debt ratio. Whether the IMF should develop and include in its template specific threshold figures that would warn of a danger zone being entered into is heavily debated. Developing a formal benchmark would somewhat automate the point at which sustainability is breached. The staff asked for the Board’s opinion in a carefully curated way that enabled a clear response: should they continue to bring all relevant information into one place (as proposed) or take a different approach and try to generate an index that “would largely remove the need for judgement?” (IMF, 2002a, 40). Framed as it was, the suggestion was unsurprisingly rejected: Directors unanimously stressed that sustainability assessments were always a matter of judgement. Callaghan (GRAY/02/721) stated that “the idea of an indicative threshold or composite indicator of debt sustainability is at odds with the thrust of the paper [IMF, 2002].” Attempts to compare the future trajectory of the debt-to-GDP ratio to a highly arbitrary rule of thumb, indicating a “danger level,” were judged illogical (Portugal, GRAY/02/728).

22However, the application of a theoretical notion of solvency to a policy template raises more fundamental issues. Solvency is deemed a theoretically clear idea, but it is difficult to quantify and usefully measure. To operationalise the notion of debt sustainability and make it useful for the IMF’s loan programmes, practical assessments or “pragmatic” assessments, as the IMF calls them, are required. The reason why the IMF begrudges the abstract formal definition of debt sustainability, calling it “precise” but “unobservable” is that it is quite simply possible to postpone generating primary surpluses to cover initial levels of debt far into the future:

The theoretical concept of sustainability based on solvency is problematic because it does not impose specific constraints on debt and deficits at any point in time … any level of debt and deficits could be compatible with the present-value budget constraint (Akyuz, 2007, 3).

23The difficulty in translating the solvency criterion from academic to pragmatic terms is evident in IMF statements. For instance, in IMF (2002a, 3), judgments about debt sustainability are in fact about “whether a country’s debt can be serviced without an unrealistically large future correction in the balance of income and expenditure.” Further on, it reads:

It is difficult to assess the feasibility of the primary surplus consistent with debt sustainability without first specifying the tax and expenditure measures that would be needed to achieve it, and judging whether these measures are sustainable over time, both technically and politically (IMF, 2002a, 20).

24Far from theoretical clarity, the notion of debt sustainability is framed in terms of “social and political” feasibility of the stipulated adjustment plans (IMF, 2002a, 5). The evaluation of whether an adjustment path is considered to be too politically or socially unfeasible is wholly controversial, and the role of the Fund in determining it contested. Bar the litmus test of social implosion, the IMF does not come up with a means to judge whether a future correction will be unrealistic and hence to accurately assess debt sustainability. Debt sustainability in practice therefore is not determined by the economics of the present value budget constraint, but rather by the cautious balance of finding the adjustment path that lies just shy of preferring default and halting debt service:

Solvency needs to be viewed in relation to the adjustment path that is not only economically feasible, but also socially and politically acceptable such that default is not a preferred option (IMF, 2002a, 5).

25Being a creditor itself, often the only one willing to supply funds in a crisis granting it the status of preferred creditor over other creditors, undermines the IMF’s neutrality in measurement. It also reconfigures debt sustainability as a political notion grounded upon the conflict between creditors and debtors. If the debt-to-GDP path is on an upward or explosive trend, this would put pressure on the IMF to mediate with private creditors, who, if defaulted upon, would not receive full repayment. As there is no explicit rationale for the Fund’s view on whether an adjustment path is considered to be too politically or socially unfeasible, the other indication that it relies on is based on the comparison with the costs of a debt restructuringchoosing adjustment over collision with other creditors. In the words of the IMF:

  • 20 In subsequent DSA templates, cross-country comparisons of size and rapidity of fiscal adjustment ar (...)

In principle, assessing whether bringing down debt ratios through a primary adjustment is too costly requires looking at the alternative by evaluating the costs of bringing down debt ratios through debt restructuring (IMF, 2011, 6).20

  • 21 For a historical example of the World Bank’s efforts see Alacevich (2016).

26The difficulty of defining a practical solvency criterion was confronted head-on, with Board members calling it “an imprecise concept” (Callaghan, GRAY/02/721) and acknowledging the “difficulty of clean distinctions between liquidity and solvency” (Lundsager and Ralyea, GRAY/02/734). As the Board members acknowledged that debt sustainability is “theoretically clear but practically ambiguous’” (Padoan and Bossone, GRAY/02/730), the discussions at the Executive Board reveal the difficulty of grounding IMF policy work in academic theory.21 In the words of two directors, they “would be hard pressed to explain how the framework would feed into the judgment of what is a politically and socially feasible adjustment effort” a core aspect of the IMF’s pragmatic definition of debt sustainability (Zoccali and Maino, GRAY/02/742). Despite technical improvements, outputs from templates alone could not determine sustainability, resulting in a mixed reception by the Board. As one of the Board directors put it, “while not a breakthrough of mythical proportions, the proposal strikes me as plain common sense” (Wijnholds, GRAY/02/726).

4. Quantifying Exceptional Access to Fund Resources

  • 22 See the discussion in Blustein (2006) and IEO (2004).
  • 23 As noted by Schadler (2016) this was left rather vague until the impetus to introduce a formal fram (...)

27Section 1 provided an overview of how the IMF’s public reputation was damaged by its handling of several crises. The failures of IMF’s policy advice and lending provoked an internal investigation, which concluded that the decision to augment the Argentinian programme in 2001 was not grounded in serious economic analysis.22 This prompted the rethinking of access to IMF resources with a view to defining more precisely the circumstances under which accessing funds over the normal limits would be granted. Prior to this, loans greater than what would ordinarily be justified were simply “exceptional”, without any formal specification by the Board about what this meant.23 This made the Fund “more vulnerable to pressure to provide exceptional access even when prospects for success are quite poor and debt burden of the sovereign is likely to be unsustainable” (IEO, 2016, 18). The revised policy laid out four explicit criteria to guide approval of exceptional access to Fund resources, one of which, in the initial wording, was “a rigorous and systematic analysis indicat[ing] that there is a high probability that debt will remain sustainable” (IMF, 2002b).

  • 24 The meeting took place on September 6, 2002, three months after the first Board meeting on the temp (...)

28In the Executive Board meeting that discussed the new criteria to guide lending, the Acting Chair, Anne Krueger, summed up the rationale that the DSA tool would quantify the second criteria and “raise the burden of proof” that the new guidelines necessitated:24

In discussing the aforementioned criteria, Directors emphasized in particular the importance of rigorous debt sustainability analyses to support requests for exceptional access (Krueger, EBM/02/94).

29Board members strongly supported the introduction of a robust DSA as a qualification of the exceptional access criteria:

Debt sustainability assessments should play a crucial role in restricting exceptional access to truly exceptional cases, as well as in making it clear when required that drastic measures such as debt restructuring are necessary to help avoid prolonged Fund lending that is undesirable (Yagi and Miyoshi, EBM/02/94).

30The reasons for this were both to “strengthen accountability and ownership” but also to necessitate “a more systematic analysis of a country’s capacity to repay the Fund, which would be closely linked with debt sustainability analyses” (Lundsager and Baukol, EBM/02/94). If exceptional finance combined with domestic adjustment as stipulated in an IMF programme could not guarantee debt sustainability in the medium term with a high probability, then a debt restructuring would be needed. Bischofberger, the Executive Director for Germany, made it clear that if the sustainability condition is not met, then the onus ought to be on private creditors accepting a reorganisation of their claims. Hence, he joked that

while staff seem to assume that ‘Capital Account Crisis plus Assumed Debt Sustainability justifies Exceptional Access,’ we would argue that ‘Capital Account Crisis plus Uncertain Debt Sustainability requires Debt Restructuring’ (Bischofberger, GRAY/02/1222).

31Although the new methodology that was being developed at the Fund was deemed crucial in determining access levels and whether the repayment of the Fund was being jeopardised, there was no full faith in the newly developed methodology either. Some Directors noted that

we are afraid that we are still far away from having an adequate analysis of debt sustainability. The new methodology that was approved by the Board recently to assess sustainability (SM/02/166) is a step in the right direction, but it is still work in progress. (Oyarzábal and Beauregard, GRAY/02/1210).

32While the discussion about the introduction of the template emphasised the supremacy of judgement over strict quantification, the same could not be said for the rationale for introducing the template in the first place which was intricately tied into providing a means to quantify the exceptional access criteria requiring a rigorous analysis that showed that debt was sustainable with a high probability.

5. Disciplining the Staff Experts through Public Scrutiny

33The 2002 introduction of the template was meant to mitigate the adhocness and undue optimism with which some country desks pursued their assessments enabling programme approval without adequate economic rationale. Although the IMF tried to redress problems of credibility through greater transparency by making known on what basis decisions were made, the way macro variables were constructed remained concealed. This left ample discretion still available for each country desk to make projections and hence model the economy in whatever way it deemed appropriate, rather than imposing a common way to generate the underlying projections. Discussions at the Board swarm around the cumbersome fact that the Fund’s baseline is inaccurate, and Directors expressed concern that the IMF’s projections were not taken seriously in the eyes of the public:

Given that debt sustainability assessments are central to key Fund decisions in program contexts, … it is important that they be viewed as being based on solid judgments and are reasonably credible (Shaalan and Farid, GRAY/02/727; emphasis added).

34Board members appeared confused as to how those projections were crafted, and what their relationship is to WEO projections. One member explained:

the paper confirms that there is a clear bias towards over optimism in the projections, either because of a bias in the WEO projections, or because of a bias in the policy assumptions underlying the baseline scenario. If the WEO projections are biased towards over-optimistic debt projections, it is not only a problem for the debt sustainability assessments, but even more so for the credibility of the Fund’s projections in general (Egilsson, EBM/03/64).

35Faced with a general unwillingness to delve into the sources of possible systematic biases, the Board attempted to reduce them. One suggestion was “to include explanations in staff reports of why the most recent forecasts were faulty” (Jacklin and Dohlman, EBM/03/64). This was deemed “useful as a disciplining device, though…is not likely to eliminate systematic bias in projections” (Jacklin and Dohlman, EBM/03/64). Another suggestion was to include scenarios that would capture how staff projections differ from consensus forecasts (Martí, EBM 03/64). The problem “with over-optimism is not one of making mistakes, but rather that of not learning from them,” Directors noted (Padoan and Bossone, GRAY/02/730). As another Directors’ statement puts it: “The goal of the exercise is to [make] it more difficult to justify programs where there is insufficient adjustment or staff use unrealistic assumptions to make programs appear ‘sustainable’” (Lundsager and Ralyea, GRAY/02/734). The US Director, who represents the most powerful country within the Fund, explicitly argued that publication of the DSA outputs would enhance the “discipline imparted by the framework” (Lundsager and Ralyea, GRAY/02/734). Publication would mean that “there are improved incentives on the Executive Board not to support a program that appears to have a limited chance of success” (Callaghan GRAY/02/721). The publication of the template was therefore seen not only as a way to make the staff more accountable to the Board, but also, as the Members argued, to make the whole institution more accountable to whoever would be affected by its policy decisions: “sustainability assessment in the public domain is in everyone’s best interest, especially the country’s,” one Director claimed (Bennett GRAY/02/729).

36The role of a public was crucialthe Board seemed to believe that IMF expertise may be somehow disciplined by being made public. The IMF surreptitiously used the public to provide the appearance of rigour and to enhance its external credibility. “A program’s credibility may be enhanced if it is apparent that the Fund has considered a range of potential outcomes when making its decision” (Callaghan GRAY/02/721). Nevertheless, the IMF staff described the interpretation of the debt sustainability outputs as “still more of an art than a science, with a large element of judgment required” (IMF, 2003, 40). The art of the debt sustainability exercise far dominated any discussion of its scientific basis at the Board level.

6. Institutional Authorship Needs the Public

37The DSA was revised between 2002 and 2003 by introducing two new scenarios: a “no policy change” scenario and a historical scenario as well as an indication of the debt stabilising primary balance. The template was tailored so that the economic reasoning that arises can yield specific and desired results. For instance, the template output could yield a sustainable trajectory by being predicated on dramatic fiscal adjustments and optimistic assumptions about growth, implying less need for debt relief. As part of the dialogue with country authorities, the template outputs could be used to pressure a country into adopting policies to compress demand and reduce incomes. Were the DSA output to suggest unsustainability, it would mean that an IMF programme was ill-defined, as domestic adjustment and IMF financing could not guarantee repayment of IMF resources, and would require an alternative course of action. If debt cannot be made sustainable through adjustment, the pressure would be on creditors to accept a restructuring of their contracts.

38With this in mind, one of the Directors remarked: “Our goal should be to ensure that the authorities face the right incentives when confronted with very high debt burdens” (Bennett, EBM/03/64). When the Board discussed the addition of more scenario analysis, the rationale was that these “could provide more persuasive arguments for the need to adjust policies” (Portugal and Tombini, EBM/03/64). To achieve this, Directors remarked that the staff needed to explain the objective of the template, its mechanics, and proposed refinements more clearly. Communication is key for soliciting the desired changes, for making it more likely that the new template can leverage policy response:

Better technical understanding by the authorities should not only lead to improved scenario identification and analysis but also, and perhaps more importantly, enhanced ownership of the courses of action that such scenarios may prompt (Callaghan and Amador, EBM/03/64).

  • 25 Two Directors remarked that “the addition of a ‘no-policy-changes’ scenario is the most useful sugg (...)

39The importance of the DSA template was also as a communication tool, “increasing the authorities’ receptivity to the findings of these analyses” (Callaghan and Amador, EBM/03/64). In particular, the introduction of a “no policy change” scenario was deemed “helpful as it quantifies the cost in terms of indebtedness of failing to carry out the measures contained in the baseline” (Martí, EBM 03/64).25 One Director admitted that “one country of my constituency recently made successful use of a ‘no policy change’ scenario to win public support for the introduction of some unpopular fiscal reforms” (Kiekens, EBM 03/64). The introduction of the historical scenario compared the adjustment plans with past experiences of the country, in response to the concern that the 2003 version of the template still yielded results “that may be too extreme or unrealistic, and thus not worthy of a policy response” (Callaghan and Amador, EBM/03/64). The ability of a table, which shows the future time path of a variable, to prompt current policy change when there is only a small chance of the time path occurring is limited. Nevertheless, this trajectory about the future would put pressure to act in the present. Improving this was part of a broader methodological discussion into new methodologies that would assign specific probabilities to the likelihood of scenarios developing.

  • 26 The rhetorical foundation and deceptiveness of the call for greater transparency in international f (...)

40The disputatious aspect of the Board was most obvious in the dilemma over whether the DSA’s results should be published. Opinions broadly fell within two main groups: one that saw publication as a means to enhance the credibility of the Fund via greater transparency, and another that saw publication as exposing the Fund.26 These opinions were underpinned by diverging views of the “public” that the publication was aimed at. A public which could react positively to publication, and thus come closer to the Fund’s view, was financial market participants:

in a capital market crisis, what matters is not the Fund’s assessment, but what the markets think about sustainability. The best chance of the markets sharing the Fund’s view is if as much information as possible which underlines the decision is made available (Callaghan, GRAY/02/721).

41In particular, releasing the information could reduce market participants’ monitoring costs (Yagi and Toyama, GRAY/02/724). Publication was vociferously opposed by those Directors who believed that the operational value of the exercise was internal decision guidance about how to use the IMF’s resources and ascertain repayment prospects (Shaalan and Farid, EBM 02/7). Representing the views of several Directors, one mentioned: “The new framework does not in itself provide sufficient grounds to ‘elevate’ the status of our debt sustainability assessments by making them public” (Shaalan and Farid, GRAY/02/727). This was because of the confidential nature of the information that the IMF is privy to, itself a product of the “special” role of the IMF in the international financial architecture.

  • 27 Technical assistance is a core element of Fund work; see Barnett and Finnemore (2004) for an overvi (...)
  • 28 The Public Information Notices intended to inform the general public about the discussions that too (...)

42The “public” was also summoned by those Directors who warned against publication because of a “risk of a considerable misinterpretation by the public” (Al-Turki, GRAY/02/735). Accepting that there may be reasons to keep certain elements confidential, for example, information on the financial sector, “the information should be provided to the Board through a separate channel” to the published version (Wijnholds, GRAY/02/726). Such a view was in keeping with the IMF’s overall transparency policy which enabled members to request suppression of sensitive economic information. Would “the market” even “understand accurately the meaning of the analytical result,” some Board members worried (Yagi and Toyama, GRAY/02/724)? Concerns were also raised regarding “some country authorities’ limited analytical capabilities to fully understand and make use of the results of the debt sustainability analysis” (EBM, 03/64), to which another Director responded with a proposal to send technical assistance to those authorities.27 This prompted further discussion on how to improve the readability of the set of tables and graphs that presented the results. Visual representation was seen as a “translation” for public use. Finally, some directors judged publication premature and suggested to wait and see. Various provisos and middle grounds were put forward, such as making publication voluntary or only partly publishing the results but not their underlying assumptions. It was decided to publish a selection of results for a year, as an experiment. After positive feedback, in 2003, quite the contrary, having been relegated to an annex in staff Reports, the main lament in this meeting was that the assessments were not public enough.28 Few however saw publication as inherently good. The sentiment that publication can “encourage open debate” was mentioned by one (Ísleifsson and Fidjestøl, GRAY/02/723) and that publication might be good because it may genuinely make “known risks that would make debts unsustainable” was only mentioned in one statement (Yagi and Toyama, GRAY/02/724).

43Given the origins of the template, the discussion about publication was also related to the outcome of other Fund policy developments, specifically, the proposal by Krueger to establish a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism (SDRM). One director mentions that “the introduction of an SDRM would strengthen the case for publication” (Yagi and Toyama, GRAY/02/724). Had the discussion in the Fund about a SDRM been fruitful, the DSA may have been destined for a far more pivotal role; if a SDRM was in place, the analysis of the newly proposed DSA template “would indicate whether an application of a debtor country to activate the SDRM is justified” claimed Wijnholds (GRAY/02/726). In that case, DSA analysis could be used more directly to effect private sector involvement by indicating how much debt had to be reduced for it to be brought to levels deemed sustainable and what the expected contribution of private sector creditors to that reduction would be. The DSA was understood as important not only as a means to guide IMF policy, but to define the “needand scopeof private sector involvement” (Von Kleist and Fabig, EBM 03/64). Though the idea for a SDRM was formally dropped in 2003 at the IMF Ministerial meeting, the life of the DSA continued with the focus on domestic contraction and surplus generation for debt repayment fortified.

7. Conclusion

44This paper showed the creation of the IMF’s Debt Sustainability Assessment template as the development of a socio-technical tool to guide decision-making of the IMF. The introduction of the template was part of a broad effort to redress policy blunders and improve appearance in the public sphere. The paper established that analytical issues are not free from political interpretation when put to operational use. The DSA embeds surplus generation instead of favourable debt dynamics for debt repayment, despite the ostensible academic clarity, the need for pragmatic definitions muddies the process of measuring debt sustainability in practice. The IMF relies on a pragmatic definition of debt sustainability that rests upon a notion of politically and socially feasible adjustment and a technical tool that provides little means to assess it. Instead, the key driver of establishing the DSA was the political decision to curtail access to extraordinary IMF loans through the introduction of a seemingly rigorous process to guide policy action. This reveals a tense amalgam of the technocratic and political dimensions of IMF work, overshadowed by an attempt to resolve credibility problems.

45The pre-formatted framework for analysis can be interpreted as a disciplinary activity to tame country desk teams to be more accountable for what they do. Introducing the template was part of an institutional curb to the tendency of producing biased analyses and a means to discipline IMF experts. In this respect, the theoretical underpinnings of the framework were less important than public perceptions in driving the analytical approach. The template attempted to resolve legitimacy problems by revealing the numbers on which decisions were made but provided little insight into how those numbers arose. This allowed continued room for reliance on overoptimism, and hence, less debt relief by creditors and placement of the burden of adjustment on the debtor. The use of collective authorship of staff documents enhanced the credibility of expertise and elicited desirable responses from the Board by framing requests for feedback in specific ways and developing scenarios to encourage policy response. There was not much on offer however as to how revealing numbers and introducing prefabricated routines for economists to fulfil could absolve the Fund from long standing legitimacy issues arising from its governance structure and nature of its policy advice.

This paper was prepared for the workshop on “Economics and Public Reason” hosted by the Centre Walras-Pareto for the History of Economic and Political Thought at the University of Lausanne in May 2018. I would like to thank the organisers and editors Harro Maas, Steven Medema, Marco Guidi, the participants of the workshop, and the members of the editorial team. The paper and earlier drafts benefited greatly from comments received by Cléo Chassonnery-Zaïgouche, James Forder, Martín Guzmán, Chris Marsh, Daniel Munevar, Mihalis Psalidopoulos, Francesco Sergi, and participants at the Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University seminar. I warmly thank Beatrice Cherrier and Michele Alacevich. Financial support by the Swiss National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.

Haut de page

Bibliographie

Archives

Al-Turki, GRAY/02/735: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506064. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/735. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Saudi Arabia.

Bennett, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003.

Bennett, GRAY/02/729: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506048. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/729. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Antigua and Barbuda, The Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Canada, Dominica, Grenada, Ireland, Jamaica, St. Kitts and Nevis, St Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines.

Bischofberger, EBM/02/94: IMF Archives. EBM/02/94–September 6, 2002 a.m. Reference: 502784. Board DOC ID: EBM/02/94–Final. September 6, 2002. Constituency: Germany.

Callaghan, GRAY/02/721: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Reference: 506024. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/721. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Australia, Kiribati, Korea, Marshall Islands, Federated States of Micronesia, Mongolia, New Zealand, Palau, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Samoa, Seychelles, Solomon Islands, Vanuatu.

Callaghan and Amador EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: Australia, Kiribati, Korea, Marshall Islands, Federated States of Micronesia, Mongolia, New Zealand, Palau, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Samoa, Seychelles, Solomon Islands, Vanuatu.

Daïri, GRAY/02/738: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506070. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/738. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Algeria, Ghana, Islamic Republic of Iran, Morocco, Pakistan, Tunisia.

Egilsson, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Iceland, Latvia, Lithuania, Norway, Sweden.

Ísleifsson and Mr. Fidjestøl, GRAY/02/723: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Reference: 506034. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/723. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Iceland, Latvia, Lithuania, Norway, Sweden.

Jacklin and Dohlman, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: United States.

Krueger, EBM/02/94: IMF Archives. EBM/02/94–September 6, 2002 a.m. Reference: 502784. Board DOC ID: EBM/02/94–Final. September 6, 2002. Acting Chair.

Lundsager and Ralyea, GRAY/02/734: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506062. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/734. June 13, 2002. Constituency: United States.

Lundsager and Baukol, EBM/02/94: IMF Archives. EBM/02/94–September 6, 2002 a.m. Reference: 502784. Board DOC ID: EBM/02/94–Final. September 6, 2002. Constituency: United States.

Martí, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Spain, Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela.

Oyarzábal and Beauregard, Gray/02/1210: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 502798. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/1210. Constituency: Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Spain, Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela.

Padoan and Mr. Bossone, GRAY/02/730: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506052. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/730. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Albania, Greece, Italy, Malta, Portugal, San Marino.

Portugal, GRAY/02/728: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506050. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/728, Rev. 1. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Brazil, Colombia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guyana, Haiti, Panama, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago.

Portugal and Tombini, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: Brazil, Colombia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guyana, Haiti, Panama, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago.

Shaalan and Farid, GRAY/02/727: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Reference: 506042. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/727. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Bahrain, Egypt, Iraq, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Maldives, Oman, Qatar, Syrian Arab Republic, United Arab Emirates, Yemen.

Varela and Alcaide GRAY/02/741: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 506076. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/741. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Spain, Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela.

Wijnholds, GRAY/02/726. IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Reference: 506040. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/726. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Armenia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Georgia, Israel, FYR Macedonia, Netherlands, Romania, Ukraine.

Yagi and Miyoshi, EBM/02/94: IMF Archives. EBM/02/94–September 6, 2002 a.m. Reference: 502784. Board DOC ID: EBM/02/94–Final. September 6, 2002. Constituency: Japan.

Yagi and Toyama, GRAY/02/724: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Reference: 506036. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/724. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Japan.

Zoccali and Maino, GRAY/02/742: IMF Archives. Executive Board Documents. Ref: 505958. Board DOC ID: Gray/02/742. June 13, 2002. Constituency: Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay.

Zurbrügg and Siegenthaler, EBM/03/64: IMF Archives. EBM/03/64–July 2, 2003 a.m. Reference: 517552. Board DOC ID: EBM/03/64–Final. July 2, 2003. Constituency: Azerbaijan, Kyrgyz Republic, Poland, Serbia and Montenegro, Switzerland, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan.

References

Alacevich, Michele. 2016. Not a Knowledge Bank: The Divided History of Development Economics and Development Organizations. Social Science History, 40(4): 627-656.

Babb, Sarah. 2001. Managing Mexico. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Babb, Sarah, and Ariel Buira. 2004. Mission Creep, Mission Push and Discretion in Sociological Perspective: The Case of IMF Conditionality. Working paper, presented at XVIII G24 Technical Group Meeting, Geneva: Switzerland.

Ban, Cornell, and Kevin Gallagher. 2015. Recalibrating Policy Orthodoxy: The IMF Since the Great Recession. Governance, 28(2): 123-164.

Bantekas, Ilias and Cephas Lumina. 2019. Sovereign Debts and Human Rights. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Barnett, Michael N., and Martha Finnemore. 2004. Rules for the World: International Organizations in Global Politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Best, Jacqueline. 2005. The Limits of Transparency: Ambiguity and the History of International Finance. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Best, Jacqueline. 2006. Civilising Through Transparency: The International Monetary Fund. In Leonard Seabrooke and Brett Bowden (eds), Global Standards of Market Civilisation. London: Routledge, 134-145.

Bird, Graham. 1996. The International Monetary Fund and Developing Countries: A Review of the Evidence and Policy Options. International Organization, 50(3): 477-511.

Blustein, Paul. 2006. And the Money Kept Rolling In (and Out): Wall Street, the IMF, and the Bankrupting of Argentina. New York: PublicAffairs.

Bonizzi, Bruno, Christina Laskaridis, and Jan Toporowski. 2019. Global Liquidity, the Private Sector and Debt Sustainability in Sub‐Saharan Africa. Development and Change, 50(5): 1430-1454.

Breen, Michael. 2013. The Politics of IMF Lending. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Broome, André and Leonard Seabrooke. 2012. Seeing like an International Organisation. New Political Economy, 17(1): 1-16.

Buira, Ariel. 2005. The Bretton Woods Institutions: Governance without Legitimacy? In Ariel Buira (ed.), Reforming the Governance of the IMF and the World Bank. London: Anthem Press, 7-44.

Chowla, Peter. 2007. A Guide for Civil Society on Getting Access to Information from the IMF. Cape Town: Global Transparency Initiative.

Chwieroth, Jeffrey. 2007. Neoliberal Economists and Capital Account Liberalization in Emerging Markets. International Organization, 61(02): 443-463.

Clift, Ben. 2018. IMF and the Politics of Austerity in the Wake of the Global Financial Crisis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Coats, A. William. 1986. Economists in International Agencies. Westport: Praeger Publishers.

Cornia, Giovanni A., Richard Jolly and Frances Stewart. 1987. Adjustment with a Human Face. New York: Clarendon Press.

de Vries, Manfred G. 1987. Balance of Payments Adjustment, 1945-1986. The IMF Experience. Washington: IMF.

Driscoll, William J., and Julie Clark. 2003. Globalization and the Poor: Exploitation or Equalizer? New York: IDEA.

Endres, Anthony M., and Grant A. Fleming. 2002. International Organizations and the Analysis of Economic Policy, 1919-1950. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Feldstein, Martin. 1998. Refocusing the IMF. Foreign Affairs, 77(2): 20-33.

Fine, Ben. 1981. Economic Theory and Ideology. Teaneck: Holmes & Meier Publishers.

Fine, Ben and Degol Hailu. 2000. Convergence and Consensus: The Political Economy of Stabilisation and Growth. SOAS Discussion Paper 2202, London: SOAS.

Fischer, Stanley. 1997. News Brief: IMF Welcomes Indonesia’s Exchange Rate Action. IMF News Brief 97/18.

Fischer, Stanley. 2005. IMF Essays from a Time of Crisis: The International Financial System, Stabilization, and Development. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Guzman, Martin and Daniel Heymann. 2015. The IMF Debt Sustainability Analysis: Issues and Problems. Journal of Globalization and Development, 6(2): 387-404.

Hall, Rodney B. 2003. The Discursive Demolition of the Asian Development Model. International Studies Quarterly, 47(1): 71–99.

Harper, Richard. 1998. Inside the IMF: An Ethnography of Documents, Technology, and Organisational Action. New York: Academic Press.

Helms, Jesse, et al. 2000. The Meltzer Commission: The Future of the IMF and the World Bank, 57 [Hearing before the Committee on Foreign Relations]. Washington: United States Senate.

Hirschman, Dan and Elizabeth P. Berman. 2014. Do Economists Make Policies? On the Political Effects of Economics. Socio-Economic Review, 12(4): 779-811.

Hooke, Augustus W. 1981. The International Monetary Fund, its Evolution, Organization, and Activities. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IEO. 2002. Evaluation of Prolonged Use of IMF Resources. Washington: International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office.

IEO. 2004. The IMF and Argentina, 1991-2001. Washington: International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office.

IEO. 2014. IMF Forecasts in the Context of Program Countries. Washington: International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office.

IEO. 2016. The IMF and the Crises in Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. Washington: International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office.

IMF. 1987. Theoretical Aspects of the Design of Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs. IMF Occasional Paper 55, Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2001. Transparency. Last Updated: April 2001. Retrieved from: https://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/ib/2001/042601b.htm.

IMF. 2002a. Assessing Sustainability. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2002b. Summing Up by the Acting Chair EBM 02/94. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2003. Sustainability Assessments, Review of Application and Methodological Refinements. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2004. Mexico: 2003 Article IV Consultation. IMF Country Report 04/254. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2011. Modernising the Framework for Fiscal Policy and Public Debt Sustainability. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

IMF. 2018. Debt Sustainability Analysis for Market-Access Countries. Last Updated: August 15, 2018. Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/dsa/mac.htm.

IMF. 2019. 2018 Review of Programme Design and Conditionality. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

Kentikelenis, Alexander E., Thomas Stubbs, and Lawrence P. King. 2016. IMF Conditionality and Development Policy Space, 1985–2014. Review of International Political Economy, 23(4): 543-582.

Kingston, Kato Gogo. 2011. The Impacts of the World Bank and IMF Structural Adjustment Programmes on Africa: The Case Study of Côte D’Ivoire, Senegal, Uganda, and Zimbabwe. Sacha Journal of Policy and Strategic Studies, 1(2): 110-130.

Koivisto, Ida. 2016. The IMF and the Transparency Turn. Minnesota Journal of International Law, 25(2): 381-420.

Lang, Valentin. 2020. The Economics of the Democratic Deficit: The Effect of IMF Programs on Inequality. The Review of International Organizations. Forthcoming.

Lang, Valentin and Andrea Presbitero. 2018. Room for Discretion? Biased Decision-making in International Financial Institutions. Journal of Development Economics, 130: 1-16.

Lumina, Cephas. 2006. An Assessment of the Human Rights Obligations of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund with Particular Reference to the World Bank’s Inspection Panel. Journal for Juridical Science, 31(2): 108-129.

Lumina, Cephas. 2013. Sovereign Debt and Human Rights. In OHCHR. Realizing the Right to Development, Essays in Commemoration of 25 Years of the United Nations Declaration on the Right to Development. Geneva: United Nations Human Rights Office of the High Commissioner.

Mata, Tiago and Steven G. Medema. 2013. Cultures of Expertise and the Public Interventions of Economists. History of Political Economy, 45(Suppl.): 1-19.

McCloskey, Deirdre N. 1992. If You’re So Smart: The Narrative of Economic Expertise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

McCloskey, Deirdre N. 1998. The Rhetoric of Economics. Chicago: University of Wisconsin Press.

Mikesell, Raymond F. 2001. The Meltzer Commission Report on International Institutions. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(4): 883-894.

Momani, Bessma. 2004. American Politicization of the International Monetary Fund. Review of International Political Economy, 11(5): 880-904.

Nissanke, Machiko and Benno Ferrarini. 2004. Debt Dynamics and Contingency Financing: Theoretical Reappraisal of the HIPC Initiative. In Tony Addison, Henrik Hansen, and Finn Tarp (eds), Debt Relief for Poor Countries. London: Palgrave, 24-58.

Oberdabernig, Doris. 2013. Revisiting the Effects of IMF Programs on Poverty and Inequality. World Development, 46: 113-142.

Porter, Theodore M. 1995. Trust in Numbers: The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Sachs, Jeffrey. 1998. The IMF and the Asian Flu. The American Prospect, 37: 16-21.

Sachs, Jeffrey. 2000. The Charade of Debt Sustainability: The World Bank and IMF Fail the World’s Poorest People by Siding with Western Donor Governments, Says Jeffrey S. Financial Times, September 26, London edition.

Schadler, Susan. 2016. Living with Rules. Background Paper BP/16-02/08. Washington: International Monetary Fund, Independent Evaluation Office.

Schavey, Aaron and William Beach. 1999. How Reliable Are IMF Economic Forecasts? Washington: The Heritage Foundation.

Seabrooke, Leonard. 2006. Resolving the International Monetary Fund’s Legitimacy Crisis. Copenhagen Business School Working Paper.

Seabrooke, Leonard. 2012. Pragmatic Numbers: The IMF, Financial Reform, and Policy Learning in Least Likely Environments. Journal of International Relations and Development, 15(4): 486-505.

Soederberg, Susanne. 2001. Grafting Stability onto Globalisation? Deconstructing the IMF’s Recent Bid for Transparency. Third World Quarterly, 22(5): 849-864.

Spraos, John. 1986. IMF Conditionality: Ineffectual, Inefficient, Mistargeted. Princeton NJ: International Finance Section, Dept. of Economics, Princeton University.

Stiglitz, Joseph. 2002. Globalization and Its Discontents. London: Penguin.

Stubbs, Thomas, Alexander Kentikelenis, David Stuckler, Martin McKee and Lawrence King. 2017. The Impact of IMF Conditionality on Government Health Expenditure: A Cross-national Analysis of 16 West African Nations. Social Science & Medicine, 174: 220-227.

Stubbs, Thomas, William Kring, Christina Laskaridis, Alexander Kentikelenis, and Kevin Gallagher. 2020. Whatever it Takes? The Global Financial Safety Net, Covid-19, and Developing Countries. World Development, 137: 105171.

Thacker, Strom C. 1999. The High Politics of IMF Lending. World Politics, 52(1): 38-75.

UNCTAD. 2009. Compendium on Debt Sustainability and Development. New York: UNCTAD.

Wade, Robert and Frank Veneroso. 1998. The Asian Crisis: The High Debt Model Versus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF Complex. New Left Review, 228(1): 3-24.

Williamson, John. 1980. Economic Theory and International Monetary Fund Policies. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 13: 255-278.

Winch, Donald. 1969. Economics and Policy. A Historical Survey. London: Hodder and Stoughton.

Woods, Ngaire. 1995. Economic Ideas and International Relations: Beyond Rational Neglect. International Studies Quarterly, 39(2): 161-180.

Woods, Ngaire. 2006. The Globalizers: The IMF, the World Bank, and Their Borrowers. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Wyplosz, Charles. 2007. Debt Sustainability Assessment: The IMF Approach and Alternatives. Graduate Institute of International Studies Working Paper 03/2007, Geneva: Graduate Institute of International Studies.

Wyplosz, Charles. 2011. Debt Sustainability Assessment: Mission Impossible. Review of Economics and Institutions, 2(3): 37.

Haut de page

Notes

1 In the IMF’s own account of its justification for policy: “there is surprisingly little readily accessible written material on its theoretical underpinnings” (IMF, 1987, 1). This is not to deny the heritage of financial programming, but rather to acknowledge the lack of explicit formulisation of how policies will lead to stated objectives (see Fine and Hailu, 2000, 6, for an examination). For a view of IMF as drawing from an ‘eclectic’ economics see Williamson (1980) and for a satirical view on the role of Fund economists see Woods (2006).

2 How ideas guide policy was often studied through the prism of ideology, a framework that drifted out of fashion as it became associated with crude interpretations of ideas. For an elaboration see Woods (1995); for older treatments see Fine (1981), McCloskey (1992) and McCloskey (1998). Recent work on the policy influence of economists points to the range of ‘cognitive infrustructures,’ socio-technical tools, and ways of reasoning of economists (Hirschman and Berman, 2014).

3 For further information on the Executive Board and how voting power is allocated according to constituency, see “IMF Executive Directors and Voting Power,” at https://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/memdir/eds.aspx [Last Updated October 2019].

4 Examples include Peru 1980 and 1984, Argentina 1983, and Brazil 1984. In Africa, in 1985, Julius Nyerere, President of Tanzania, resigned rather than agree to an IMF programme; Zambia’s programme was suspended by its President in 1987 following extensive food riots; in Burkina Faso, military leader and President Thomas Sankara, resisting the IMF programmes, called for widespread debt repudiations. Numerous riots have broken out, at times with hundreds left dead as in the Dominican Republic and in Venezuela, following implementation of IMF policy that led to skyrocketing increases in the price of medicines and basic food stuffs. Eliminating subsidies on basic goods and liberalising sectors places constraints upon on governments’ capacity to provide public services, leading to increased poverty, with knock-on effects on a range of human rights concerns (see Lumina, 2006; 2013). For recent evidence of adverse socioeconomic impacts of IMF conditionality see Kingston (2011), Lang (2020), Oberdabernig (2013) and Stubbs et al., (2017) and for recent evidence of failure to meet its policy promises see Stubbs et al. (2020).

5 Exceptions to this rule include Board minutes relating to members’ request for resources, where the wait is five years. For documents classified as confidential or similar, release depends on the discretion of the Managing Director.

6 The IMF’s handling of the South East Asian Crisis was heavily criticised for the politicisation of conditionality through reforms far severer than deemed necessary (see Feldstein, 1998; Stiglitz, 2002; Sachs, 1998; 2000; Wade and Veneroso, 1998). IMF blunders were put to the US Senate via the Meltzer Commission (see Helms et al., 2000; Mikesell, 2001; Feldstein, 1998; and for a defence, Fischer, 2005).

7 The relevant decision by the Board can be found in IMF (2002b).

8 For the impact of subsequent crises on the IMF see Ban and Gallagher (2015), Clift (2018) and Stubbs et al. (2020).

9 The attempt by the IMF to address concerns about transparency is critically examined in Best (2005), Best (2006), Koivisto (2016) and Soedeberg (2001).

10 When a member of EXR published a pamphlet on the IMF’s organisation, evolution and activities in 1981 (Hooke, 1981) it was the first comprehensive description that had been made available to the public since the early 1960s.

11 The template pertains to assessments of debt sustainability for countries with market access; for lower income countries reliant predominantly on concessional financing a separate template was subsequently introduced in 2005. For evidence of malleability in the mechanical application of the low-income country framework see Lang and Presbitero (2018).

12 The IMF produces periodic country reports for countries that are in an IMF programme as well as annually for all its members as part of routine surveillance.

13 The dynamic budget constraint is solved through the transversality condition, a terminal condition that ensures that debts will not be repaid by some last-minute dash for further borrowing, but rather, that over the infinite time horizon, debts will be repaid through surpluses.

14 See IMF (2002, 5) for a fuller exposition.

15 Over time, the template has become widely distributed and publicly available. The IMF has increased its resources to educating both country officials and members of the public on conducting debt sustainability analyses.

16 For the recent shift towards growth optimism and how this yields risky programmes by design see IMF (2019). New and older studies also find that the larger the IMF loan, the more optimistic the projection (IEO, 2014; Schavey and Beach, 1999).

17 The staff state that the precise formulation of the template is ongoing and subject to continuous modification and revision. The 2003 template builds on the 2002 version by adding more features, ushering in new methods to hone down the accuracy of the exercise. It has since been clarified and revised several times with details of revisions available at IMF (2018).

18 Subsequent template vintages have sought to address some of the concerns.

19 Statements are referenced by the name of director(s) followed by the document type and are listed in the Reference list along with the country or countries that Directors’ statements represent.

20 In subsequent DSA templates, cross-country comparisons of size and rapidity of fiscal adjustment are introduced to ascertain how the stipulated adjustment compares.

21 For a historical example of the World Bank’s efforts see Alacevich (2016).

22 See the discussion in Blustein (2006) and IEO (2004).

23 As noted by Schadler (2016) this was left rather vague until the impetus to introduce a formal framework emerged from the IMF’s experiences in the 1990s and early 2000s.

24 The meeting took place on September 6, 2002, three months after the first Board meeting on the template.

25 Two Directors remarked that “the addition of a ‘no-policy-changes’ scenario is the most useful suggestion in the staff paper. It would provide an indirect estimate of the potential benefits of the discussed policy changes, thus providing both staff and authorities with a powerful argument for the need of the measures” (Zurbrügg and Siegenthaler, EBM/03/64).

26 The rhetorical foundation and deceptiveness of the call for greater transparency in international financial architecture is examined by Best (2005).

27 Technical assistance is a core element of Fund work; see Barnett and Finnemore (2004) for an overview.

28 The Public Information Notices intended to inform the general public about the discussions that took place were released with some delay; in the case of the 2002 meeting 27 days after it took place, and two months and three days after the 2003 meeting took place.

Haut de page

Table des illustrations

Titre Figure 1: External Debt Sustainability Analysis in Mexico’s 2003 Article IV Consultation
Crédits Source: IMF (2004, 45)
URL http://0-journals-openedition-org.catalogue.libraries.london.ac.uk/oeconomia/docannexe/image/9857/img-1.jpg
Fichier image/jpeg, 224k
Titre Figure 2: Stress Tests for External Debt Ratio in 2003 Mexico Article IV Consultation
Crédits Source: IMF (2004, 45)
URL http://0-journals-openedition-org.catalogue.libraries.london.ac.uk/oeconomia/docannexe/image/9857/img-2.jpg
Fichier image/jpeg, 144k
Titre Figure 3: Example of a Visual Representation of Debt Sustainability Shocks
Légende Source: IMF (2004, 19)
URL http://0-journals-openedition-org.catalogue.libraries.london.ac.uk/oeconomia/docannexe/image/9857/img-3.jpg
Fichier image/jpeg, 157k
Haut de page

Pour citer cet article

Référence papier

Christina Laskaridis, « More of an Art than a Science: The IMF’s Debt Sustainability Analysis and the Making of a Public Tool »Œconomia, 10-4 | 2020, 789-818.

Référence électronique

Christina Laskaridis, « More of an Art than a Science: The IMF’s Debt Sustainability Analysis and the Making of a Public Tool »Œconomia [En ligne], 10-4 | 2020, mis en ligne le 01 décembre 2020, consulté le 13 octobre 2024. URL : http://0-journals-openedition-org.catalogue.libraries.london.ac.uk/oeconomia/9857 ; DOI : https://0-doi-org.catalogue.libraries.london.ac.uk/10.4000/oeconomia.9857

Haut de page

Auteur

Christina Laskaridis

Open University. christina.laskaridis@open.ac.uk

Articles du même auteur

Haut de page

Droits d’auteur

CC-BY-NC-ND-4.0

Le texte seul est utilisable sous licence CC BY-NC-ND 4.0. Les autres éléments (illustrations, fichiers annexes importés) sont « Tous droits réservés », sauf mention contraire.

Haut de page
Rechercher dans OpenEdition Search

Vous allez être redirigé vers OpenEdition Search